A PDF version of this post is available for download here.
Summary
- In an ideal world, all investors would outperform their benchmarks. In reality, outperformance is a zero-sum game: for one investor to outperform, another must underperform.
- If achieving outperformance with a certain strategy is perceived as being “easy,” enough investors will pursue that strategy such that its edge is driven towards zero.
- Rather, for a strategy to outperform in the long run, it has to be hard enough to stick with in the short run that it causes investors to “fold,” passing the alpha to those with the fortitude to “hold.”
- In other words, for a strategy to outperform in the long run, it must underperform in the short run. We call this The Frustrating Law of Active Management.
A few weeks ago, AQR published a piece titled Craftsmanship Alpha: An Application to Style Investing[1], to which Cliff Asness wrote a further perspective piece titled Little Things Mean a Lot[2].
We’ll admit that we are partial to the title “craftsmanship alpha” because portfolio craftsmanship is a concept we spend a lot of time thinking about. In fact, we have a whole section titled Portfolio Craftsmanship on the Investment Philosophy section of our main website.[3] We further agree with Cliff: little things do mean a lot. We even wrote a commentary about it in May titled Big Little Details[4].
But there was one quote from Cliff, in particular, that inspires this week’s commentary:
Let’s just make up an example. Imagine there are ten independent (uncorrelated) sources of “craftsmanship alpha” and that each adds 2 basis points of expected return at the cost of 20 basis points of tracking error from each (against some idea of a super simple “non-crafted” alternative.) Each is thus a 0.10 Sharpe ratio viewed alone. Together they are expected to add 20 basis points to the overall factor implementation inducing 63 basis points of tracking error (20 basis points times the square-root of ten). That’s a Sharpe ratio of 0.32 from the collective craftsmanship (in addition to the basic factor returns).
[…]
But, as many have noted in other contexts, a Sharpe ratio like 0.32 can be hard to live with. Its chance of subtracting from your performance in a given year is about 37%. Its chance of subtracting over five years is about 24%. And, wait for it… over twenty years the chance it subtracts is still about 8%. That’s right. There’s a non-trivial chance your craftsmanship is every bit as good as you think, and it subtracts over two full decades, perhaps the lion’s share of your career. Such is the unforgiving, uncaring math.
Whether it is structural alpha, style premia, or craftsmanship alpha: we believe that the very uncertainty and risk that manifests as (expected) tracking error is a necessary component for the alpha to exist in the first place.
The “unforgiving, uncaring math” that is a result – the fact that you can do everything right and still get everything wrong – is a concept that in the past we have titled The Frustrating Law[5] of Active Management.
Defining The Frustrating Law of Active Management
We define The Frustrating Law of Active Management as:
For any disciplined[6] investment approach to outperform over the long run, it must experience periods of underperformance in the short run.
As if that were not frustrating enough a concept – that even if we do everything right, we still have to underperform from time-to-time – we add this corollary:
For any disciplined investment approach to underperform over the long run, it must experience periods of outperformance in the short run.
In other words, even if a competing manager does everything wrong, they should still be rewarded with outperformance at some point. Talk about adding insult to injury.
For the sake of brevity, we will only explore the first half of the law in this commentary. Note, however, that the second law is simply the inverse case of the first. After all, if we found an investment strategy that consistently underperformed, we could merely inverse the signals and have a strategy that consistently outperforms. If the latter is impossible, so must be the former.
For it to work, it has to be hard
Let’s say we approach you with a new investment strategy. We’ve discovered the holy grail: a strategy that always outperforms. It returns an extra 2% over the market, consistently, every year, after fees.
Ignoring reasonable skepticism for a moment, would you invest? Of course you would. This is free money we’re talking about here!
In fact, everyone we pitch to would invest. Who wouldn’t want to be invested in such a strategy? And here, we hit a roadblock.
Everyone can’t invest. Relative performance is, after all, zero sum: for some to outperform, others must underperform. Our extra return has to come from somewhere.
If we do continue to accept money into our strategy, we will begin to approach and eventually exceed capacity. As we put money to work, we will create impact and inform the market, driving prices away from us. As we try to buy, prices will be driven up and as we try to sell, prices will be driven down. By chasing price, our outperformance will deteriorate.
And it needn’t even be us trading the strategy. Once people learn about what we are doing – and how easy it is to make money – others will begin to employ the same approach. Increasing capital flow will continue to erode the efficacy of the edge as more and more money chases the same, limited opportunities. The growth is likely to be exponential, quickly grinding our money machine quickly to a halt.
So, the only hope of keeping a consistent edge is in a mixture of: (1) keeping the methodology secret, (2) keeping our deployed capital well below capacity, and (3) having a structural moat (e.g. first-mover advantage, relationship-driven flow, regulatory edge, non-profit-seeking counter-party, etc).
While we believe that all asset managers have the duty to ensure #2 remains true (we highly recommend reading Alpha or Assets by Patrick O’Shaughnessy[7]), #1 pretty much precludes any manager actually trying to raise assets (with, perhaps, a few limited exceptions in the hedge fund world that can raise assets on brand alone).
The takeaway here is that if an edge is perceived as being easy to implement (i.e. not case #3 above) and easy to achieve, enough people will do it to the point that the edge is driven to zero.
Therefore, if an edge is known by many (e.g. most style premia like value, momentum, carry, defensive, trend, etc), then for it to persist over the long run, the outperformance must be difficult to capture. Remember: for outperformance to exist, weak hands must at some point “fold” (be it for behavioral or risk-based reasons), passing the alpha to strong hands that can “hold.”
This is not just a case of perception, either. Financial theory tells us that a strategy cannot always outperform its benchmark with certainty. After all, if it did, we would have an arbitrage: we could go long the strategy, short the benchmark, and lock in certain profit. As markets loathe (or, perhaps, love) arbitrage, such an opportunity should be rapidly chased away. Thus, for a disciplined strategy to generate alpha over the long run, it must go through periods of underperformance in the short-run.
Can We Diversify Away Difficulty?
Math tells us that we should be able to stack the benefits of multiple, independent alpha sources on top of each other and simultaneously benefit from potentially reduced tracking error due to diversification.
Indeed, mathematically, this is true. It is why diversification is known as the only free lunch in finance.
This certainly holds for beta, which derives its value from economic activity. In theory, everyone can hold the Sharpe ratio optimal portfolio and introduce cash or leverage to hit their appropriate risk target.
Alpha, on the other hand, is explicitly captured from the hands of other investors. Contrary to the Sharpe optimal portfolio, everyone cannot hold the Information ratio optimal portfolio at the same time[8]. Someone needs to be on the other side of the trade.
Consider three strategies that all outperform over the long run: strategy A, strategy B, and strategy C. Does our logic change if we learn that strategy C is simply 50% strategy A plus 50% strategy B? Of course not! For C to continue to outperform over the long run, it must remain sufficiently difficult to stick with in the short-run that it causes weak hands to fold.
Conclusion
For a strategy to outperform in the long run, it has to be perceived as hard: hard to implement or hard to hold. For public, liquid investment styles that most investors have access to, it is usually a case of the latter.
This law is underpinned by two facts. First, relative performance is zero-sum, requiring some investors to underperform for others to outperform. Second, consistent outperformance violates basic arbitrage theories.
While coined somewhat tongue-in-cheek, we think this law provides an important reminder to investors about reasonable expectations. As it turns out, the proof is not always in the eating of the pudding. In fact, track records can be entirely misleading as validators of an investment process. As Cliff pointed out, even if our alpha source has a Sharpe ratio of 0.32, there is an 8% chance that it subtracts from performance over the next 20-years.
Conversely, even negative alpha sources can show beneficial performance by chance. An alpha source with a Sharpe ratio of -0.32 has an 8% chance that it adds to performance over the next 20-years.
And that’s why we call it The Frustrating Law of Active Management. For investors and asset managers alike, there is little more frustrating than knowing that to continue working over the long run, good strategies have to do poorly, and poor strategies have to do well over shorter timeframes.
[1] https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3034472
[2] https://www.aqr.com/cliffs-perspective/little-things-mean-a-lot
[3] https://www.thinknewfound.com/investment-philosophy
[4] https://blog.thinknewfound.com/2017/05/big-little-details/
[5] To be clear that we don’t mean a “law” in the sense of an inviolable, self-evident axiom. In truth, our “law” is much closer to a “theory.”
[6] The disciplined component here is very important. By this, we mean a strategy that applies a consistent set of rules. We do not mean, here, a bifurcation of systematic versus discretionary. Over the years, we’ve met a large number of discretionary managers who apply a highly disciplined approach. Rather, we mean those aspects of an investment strategy that can be codified and turned into a set of systematically applied rules.
Thus, even a discretionary manager can be thought of as a systematic manager plus a number of idiosyncratic deviations from those rules. The deviations must be idiosyncratic, by nature. If there was a consistent reason for making the deviations, after all, the reason could be codified itself. Thus, true discretion only applies to unique, special, and non-repeatable situations.
Note that the discipline does not preclude randomness. You could, for example, flip a coin and use the result to make an investment decision every month. So long as the same set of rules is consistently applied, we believe The Frustrating Law of Active Management applies.
[7] http://investorfieldguide.com/alpha-or-assets/
[8] Well, technically they can if everyone is a passive investor. In this case, however, the information ratio would be undefined, with zero excess expected return and zero tracking error.
It’s Long/Short Portfolios All The Way Down
By Corey Hoffstein
On November 6, 2017
In Portfolio Construction, Weekly Commentary
There is a PDF version of this post available for download here.
Summary
The Importance of Long/Short Portfolios
Anybody who has read our commentaries for some time has likely found that we have a strong preference for simple models. Justin, for example, has a knack for turning just about everything into a conversation about coin flips and their associated probabilities. I, on the other hand, tend to lean towards more hand-waving, philosophical arguments (e.g. The Frustrating Law of Active Management[1] or that every strategy is comprised of a systematic and an idiosyncratic component[2]).
While not necessarily 100% accurate, the power of simplifying mental models is that it allows us to explore concepts to their – sometimes absurd – logical conclusion.
One such model that we use frequently is that the difference between any two portfolios can be expressed as a dollar-neutral long/short portfolio. For us, it’s long/short portfolios all the way down.
This may sound like philosophical gibberish, but let’s consider a simple example.
You currently hold Portfolio A, which is 100% invested in the S&P 500 Index. You are thinking about taking that money and investing it entirely into Portfolio B, which is 100% invested in the Barclay’s U.S. Aggregate Bond Index. How can you think through the implications of such a change?
One way of thinking through such changes is that recognizing that there is some transformation that takes us from Portfolio A to portfolio B, i.e. Portfolio A + X = Portfolio B.
We can simply solve for X by taking the difference between Portfolio B and Portfolio A. In this case, that difference would be a portfolio that is 100% long the Barclay’s U.S. Aggregate Bond Index and 100% short the S&P 500 Index.
Thus, instead of saying, “we’re going to hold Portfolio B,” we can simply say, “we’re going to continue to hold Portfolio A, but now overlay this dollar-neutral long/short portfolio.”
This may seem like an unnecessary complication at first, until we realize that any differences between Portfolio A and B are entirely captured by X. Focusing exclusively on the properties of X allows us to isolate and explore the impact of these changes on our portfolio and allows us to generalize to cases where we hold allocation to X that are different than 100%.
Re-Thinking Fees with Long/Short Portfolios
Perhaps most relevant, today, is the use of this framework in the context of fees.
To explore, let’s consider the topic in the form of an example. The iShares S&P 500 Value ETF (IVE) costs 0.18%, while the iShares S&P 500 ETF (IVV) is offered at 0.04%. Is it worth paying that extra 0.14%?
Or, put another way, does IVE stand a chance to make up the fee gap?
Using the long/short framework, one way of thinking about IVE is that IVE = IVV + X, where X is the long/short portfolio of active bets.
But are those active bets worth an extra 0.14%?
First, we have to ask, “how much of the 0.18% fee is actually going towards IVV and how much is going towards X?” We can answer this by using a concept called active share, which explicitly measures how much of IVE is made up of IVV and how much it is made up of X.
Active share can be easily explained with an example.[3] Consider having a portfolio that is 50% stocks and 50% bonds, and you want to transition it to a portfolio that is 60% stocks and 40% bonds.
In essence, your second portfolio is equal to your first plus a portfolio that is 10% long stocks and 10% short bonds. Or, equivalently, we can think of the second portfolio as equal to the first plus a 10% position in a portfolio that is 100% long stocks and 100% short bonds.
Through this second lens, that 10% number is our active share.
Returning to our main example, IVE has a reported active share of 42% against the S&P 500[4].
Hence, we can say that IVE = 100% IVV + 42% X. This also means that 0.14% of the 0.18% fee is associated with our active bets, X. (We calculate this as 0.18% – 0.04% x 100%.)
If we take 0.14% and divide it by 42%, we get the implicit fee that we are paying for our active bets. In this case, 0.333%.
So now we have to ask ourselves, “do we think that a long/short equity portfolio can return at least 0.333%?” We might want to dive more into exactly what that long/short portfolio looks like (i.e. what are the actual active bets being made by IVE versus IVV), but it does not seem so outrageous. It passes the sniff test.
What if IVE were actually 0.5% instead? Now we would say that 0.46% of the 0.5% is going towards our 42% position in X. And, therefore, the implicit amount we’re paying for X is actually 1.09%.
Am I confident that an equity long/short value portfolio can clear a hurdle of 1.09% with consistency? Much less so. Plus, the fee now eats a much more significant part of any active return generated. E.g. If we think the alpha from the pure long/short portfolio is 3%, now 1/3rd of that is going towards fees.
With this framework in mind, it is no surprise active managers have historically struggled so greatly to beat their benchmarks. Consider that according to Morningstar[5], the dollar-weighted average fee paid to passive indexes was 0.25% in 2000, whereas it was 1% for active funds.
If we assume a very generous 50% active share for those active funds, we can use the same math as before to find that we were, in essence, paying a 2.00% fee for the active bets. That’s a high hurdle for anyone to overcome.
And the closet indexers? Let’s be generous and assume they had an active share of 20% (which, candidly, is probably high if we’re calling them closet indexers). This puts the implied fee at 4%! No wonder they struggled…
Today, the dollar weighted average expense ratio for passive funds is 0.17% and for active funds, it’s 0.75%. To have an implied active fee of less than 1%, active funds at that level will have to have an active share of at least 30%.[6]
Conclusion
As the ETF fee wars rage on, and the fees for standard benchmarks plummeting on a near-daily basis, the only way an active manager can continue to justify a high fee is with an exceptionally high active share.
We would argue that those managers caught in-between – with average fees and average active share – are those most at risk to be disintermediated. Most investors would actually be better off by splitting the exposure into cheaper beta solutions and more expensive, high active share solutions. Bar-belling low fee beta with high active share, higher fee managers may actually be cheaper to incorporate than those found the middle of the road.
The largest problem with this approach, in our minds, is behavioral. High active share should mean high tracking error, which means significant year-to-year deviation from a benchmark. So long as investors still review their portfolios on an itemized basis, this approach runs the risk of introducing greater behavioral foibles than a more moderated – yet ultimately more expensive – approach.
[1] https://blog.thinknewfound.com/2017/10/frustrating-law-active-management/
[2] https://twitter.com/choffstein/status/880207624540749824
[3] Perhaps it is “examples” all the way down.
[4] See https://tools.alphaarchitect.com
[5] https://corporate1.morningstar.com/ResearchLibrary/article/810041/us-fund-fee-study–average-fund-fees-paid-by-investors-continued-to-decline-in-2016/
[6] We are not saying that we need a high active share to predict outperformance (https://www.aqr.com/library/journal-articles/deactivating-active-share). Rather, a higher active share reduces the implicit fee we are paying for the active bets.